Trade Liberalization and Chinas Food Economy in the 21st Century: Implications to Chinas National Food Security
Jikun Huang, Chunlai Chen
Center for Chinese Agricultural Policy
Chinese Academy of Agricultural Sciences
Scott Rozelle
University of California, Davis
and
Francis Tuan
ERS, USDA
Trade Liberalization and Chinas Food Economy in the 21st Century: Implications to Chinas National Food Security
I. Introduction
Since the economic reform initiated in the late 1978, Chinas economy has been growing substantially. The annual growth rate of Chinas GDP was 8.5% in 1979-84, 9.7% in 1985-95 and 9.2% in 1996-97 (Table 1). Despite the Asian financial crisis since 1997, China's economy continued to grow though at a slower rate than the previous years. The GDP grew at 7.8% in 1998 and nearly 8% in the first half year of 1999 (compared to first six months of 1998), the growth rates were still among the highest in the world (SSB, 1999).
Chinas foreign trade has been expanding even more rapidly than its overall economic growth (Table 1). With the rapid growth of the external sector, foreign trade has been playing increasing role in the national economy since reform started in the later 1970s. Chinas trade to GDP ratio increased from 13% in 1980 to 36% in 1997 (Table 2).
During the same period, the total value of Chinas agricultural trade increased from US$9.29 billion to US$25.15 billion, with an annual growth rate of 6.0% (Huang and Chen, 1999b). China applied to join GATT and then the World Trade Organization (WTO) in 1986, although China has not been accepted as a member of the WTO, China has committed to comprehensively implement the Uruguay Round agreements upon its accession into the WTO.
With 13 years negotiation on Chinas WTO accession, particular the recent progress made during Premier Zhu Rongjis visit to the United States in April of 1999, it is likely that China will join the WTO before the end of 1999. The sheer size of Chinas economy and its rapid growth will make China a crucial player in the future development of world markets for inputs and outputs of food and agricultural products, agribusiness, and industry. While the negotiation is still undergoing, there has been also growing concern on the impacts on Chinas accession to WTO on Chinas domestic agricultural production, price and market, employment and the farmers income, particularly in the short term. How to sustain agricultural growth, achieve food security, and increase farmers income with the process of agricultural trade liberalization has been the priority concern of not only the policy makers but also the farmers. What are the impacts of trade liberalization on Chinas agricultural production? What are the implications of the trade liberalization to Chinas food security and world trade? What are the policy implications of the changes in the economy resulted from the trade liberalization in the future?
The answers to these questions are by no means clear. While all studies show that both Chinas economy as a whole and the rest of the world will benefit from the Chinas WTO accession, their impacts on Chinas agriculture are highly debated. Some researchers claim that the impacts of Chinas accession to the WTO on Chinas agricultural production and world trade are marginal (Anderson, 1997). Others believe that the impacts of trade liberalization on Chinas agricultural sector should not be understated (Wang, 1997; the State Council, 1998; Huang, 1998; Huang and Chen, 1999a, 1999b).
To have a better understanding of the questions raised above, the overall goals of this study are to examine the reform process of Chinas foreign trade sector and its impact on Chinas agriculture trade patterns in the past 2 decades, to explore the possible effects of trade liberalization on Chinas food balance and its implication to agricultural trade, and to provide some policy recommendations for the smooth implementation of agricultural trade liberalization in China.
The paper is structured as follows. The next two sections present an overview of the reform in Chinas external sector and its impacts on agricultural trade in the past 2 decades. In the fourth section, the effects of the trade liberalization on Chinas agriculture are projected using a agricultural sector wise general equilibrium model. Finally, conclusions and policy implications from the study are summarized in the last section.
II. Reform in Chinas External Sector and Agricultural Trade Pattern
Foreign Trade Regime in the Pre-Reform Period (Before 1979)
After the founding of the Peoples Republic of China in 1949, China soon established the socialist planning economy. Under the desire of accelerating the national economic growth and industrialization, like many other developing countries, China adopted the "import substitution" industrialization strategy, and established a highly centralized and planned foreign trade regime. Under this foreign trade regime, export was aimed to serve import and foreign trade was aimed to serve national industrialization (Lardy, 1992 and 1995). This planned foreign trade regime was implemented strictly under the rules and regulations on trade organization and operation, trade management and control, trade planning, and trade financing.
The foreign trade rights were granted by the Ministry of Foreign Trade to only a few state owned enterprises (SOE) or corporations. For a national as a whole, only 12 national specialized general foreign trade corporations and their port sub-corporations had the trading rights. These 12 national specialized general foreign trade corporations and their port sub-corporations monopolized all foreign trade business in China before 1978. For example, foreign trade of agricultural products was monopolized by COFCO, China National Native and Animal Products Import and Export Corporation, and China National Textiles Import and Export Corporation.
Foreign trade management and control were mainly based on government administrative means (Huang and Chen, 1999a). The state foreign trade plan was mandatory and covered all aspects of foreign trade, including foreign trade procurement, transfer and allocation, export, import, foreign exchange earnings and payments and so on. Foreign trade corporations were not responsible for making profits and losses from trade. The Ministry of Finance was responsible for all profits and losses and also provided all working capital to foreign trade corporations.
The Early Reform Period (1979-1987)
China implemented a series of important policy and measures in the early period of foreign trade reform. The highly centralized and monopolized foreign trade operation system was gradually reformed and partially decentralized by establishing more new trade-ports and granting more corporations and production firms the direct foreign trading rights. From 1979 to 1987, more than 2,200 foreign trade corporations were established, increasing 11 times than the number of foreign trade corporations in 1979. The single mandatory planning foreign trade system was also replaced by a new system that introduced the guidance plan and market adjustments to the old mandatory plan in order to improve the trade response to the domestic and international market changes in 1985. This new foreign trade system covers most majority products except a few bulk products which are important to the national economy and peoples livelihood, including most agricultural products (mainly grains), and the imports of whole set of equipment and technology.
The reform of foreign trade management system was gradually performed by reducing government direct administrative intervention and by introducing trade instruments to manage foreign trade. In 1980 China established the quota system and restored the licensing system to manage import and export of commodities including agricultural products. Meantime, the experiments on linking foreign trade corporations with production firms were carried out in order to improve the quality of export products and increase competitiveness in the international market in 1982. To promote export, China introduced export tax rebate in the early 1080s, and experienced a trade contract responsibility system in 1987 (see the next sub-section for details of the contract system).
Toward A More Market-Oriented Trade Reform Period after 1987
Despite the progress made in reforming Chinas foreign trade sector in the early stage of reform, the fundamental problems in the foreign trade sector remained, namely the efficiency of the trade and the budget financing system. The foreign trade reform since the late 1980s has been trying to fully implement the trade contract responsibility system and to introduce a more market-oriented trade regime in the economy. Other major trade policies include regional open door policies, foreign direct investment policies, fiscal policies, monetary policies, foreign exchange policies, and foreign trade control (tariff and non-tariff measures) policies.
Foreign Trade Contract Responsibility System
Drawing on the experiences of the foreign trade contract responsibility system experimented on the national specialized general foreign trade corporations in 1987, the foreign trade contract responsibility system has been implemented national wise since 1988-90. The contract system consisted of three major components: foreign exchange earnings of exports, the shares of foreign exchange earned between the central government and trade agencies, and overall economic efficiency.
To facilitate the implementation of foreign trade contract responsibility system, the Chinese government introduced a number of complementary measures. The foreign exchange control (use right) was relaxing. Although China introduced foreign exchange retention system that allowed the enterprises and local governments to retain certain proportion of foreign exchange earned through their expanded exports as the early as 1979, the use of the retained foreign exchange had been strictly controlled by the central government before 1987. The 1988 policy allowed local governments and enterprises to have their own rights in disposal or use of the retained foreign exchange through the foreign exchange swap centers that was established in the same year in the key cities of each provinces and Special Economic Zones (SEZs). Enterprises, including foreign funded enterprises, could purchase and sell foreign exchange at the foreign exchange swap center at the managed floating exchange rate. This policy had been in effective until the unification of the official and swap foreign exchange market in 1994. In December 1996 RMB became convertible on the current account. Other polices related to the responsibility system include providing more decision-making powers to local governments and enterprises in granting foreign trading rights to foreign trade enterprises, in FDI for the coastal economic areas in approving foreign direct investment, in controlling quotas and licenses, and in importing materials for processing.
Export Subsidies
Under the planned foreign trade regime, foreign trade corporations were not responsible for their profits and losses incurred from foreign trade business. The Ministry of Finance was not only took all profits and covered all losses but also provided all working capital for foreign trade corporations. Because of the distorted domestic pricing system, the export subsidies were a common phenomenon under the planned foreign trade regime. China fixed its export subsidy for 1988-90 to a level equal to about 4% of the total export value in the 1987 in order to curb the rising trend of the subsidy that caused not only the financial difficulty, but also inefficiency of the trade sector. Finally, the government decided to phase out export subsidies to all foreign trade corporations in 1991.
Export Tax Rebate
To promote export and to increase the competitiveness of Chinas export commodities in the international market, China started to use export tax rebate in 1983 for only 17 export commodities on an experimental base. This policy then had been extended to cover more export commodities since the mid-1980s and apply to almost all export commodities after 1988. The type of export tax rebate has included the product tax, value-added tax, business tax and special consumption tax since 1988.
The principle for the rate of export tax rebate is that exports should be zero-rated and eligible for a full rebate on the value-added tax (13% for some selected commodities mentioned above and 17% for all other commodities) and consumption tax paid. This export tax rebate policy applies to all export commodities except crude oil, refined oil, export commodities for foreign assistance, commodities prohibited for export by state, and sugar. However, in the actual implementation of the new export tax rebate, the claims for rebates on value-added tax paid on inputs imported for export production substantially exceeded expectations, thus in 1995 the rebate on inputs purchased for export production was reduced to 14% and latter to 9%. The value-added tax on inputs purchased for export production imposes an effective net tax on exports. Improvement in the administration of the law that would raise the collection rate and allow a return to zero rating for exports would substantially improve trade performance (World Bank, 1997).
Trade Related Monetary Policies
Chinas monetary policy refers to the measures which the Peoples Bank of China, the central bank, takes in controlling the money and credit supply to bring about the desired changes in the economy. Since economic reform China has been gradually moving away from a planned economy towards a market economy. As a result, China has been increasingly using the monetary policy as one of the main means in its macro-economic adjustment and control. To help and promote foreign trade after phasing out export subsidies, China established the Import and Export Bank to provide the trade cooperatives with import and export credits in 1994
Foreign Exchange Policies
With the unification of the two-tier foreign exchange rate systems, the foreign exchange retention system has been finally abolished since 1994, and the RMB has become convertible on the current account since 1996. Historically, the overvaluation of domestic currency for trade protection purposes has reduced exportable incentives. Real exchange rates remained constant and even appreciated during the 30 years prior to reforms, but depreciated rapidly after reforms, with the exception of several years following the high domestic price inflation of 1985. From 1978 to 1992, the real exchange rate depreciated more than 400 percent. Economic productivity growth and technological innovation in agriculture, foreign trade, and industry contributed to low inflation and the success of exchange rate adjustments. Within Asia, China is second only to Indonesia in aggressively adjusting exchange rates over the last two decades except for recent 5 years (real exchange rate has been appreciated by about 30 percent from 1992 to 1997). Falling exchange rates increased export competitiveness and so have contributed to Chinas phenomenal export growth record (i.e. non-grain food products) and the spectacular national economic performance of the 1980s.
Tariffs and Non-Tariff Measures
Chinas average tariff was 47.2% in 1991, one of the highest countries in the world (World Bank, 1997). Since then, China has gradually reduced its import tariff rates. In April 1996 China reduced its import tariff rates for more than 4,900 items, lowering the simple average tariff rate from 35.9% to 23%. In October 1997 China further reduced the import tariff rates for more than 4,800 items and brought down its simple average tariff rate from 23% to 17% (23.6% for agriculture). Currently, relevant departments are studying specific products and implementation steps for tariff reduction. Apart from that, China has actively participated in the consultations on the tariff-related actions for early voluntary sectoral liberalization.
According to Chinas 1997 Individual Action Plan submitted to APEC, in the short term China committed to reduce its average tariff rate to 15% by 2000 (Table 3). In the medium and long term from 2001 to 2020, China will reduce its average tariff rate for industrial products to 10% by 2005. China will eliminate tariffs of 185 information technology products by 2005 except a few of them by 2007. China will take actions actively and steadily toward tariff reduction in sectors identified for early voluntary sectoral liberalization in accordance with relevant agreement or arrangement concluded by APEC members. And China will further lower the overall tariff level.
During the 1980s China extensively used quotas and licensing to control its foreign trade. However, since the early 1990s China has progressively and drastically reduced the number of items subject to export and import quotas and licensing administration. The products subject to quota, licensing and other import control measures accounted for only 5% of the total import tariff lines in 1998.
In sum, through nearly 20 years reform, Chinas foreign trade regime has gradually changed from a highly centralized, planned and import substitution regime to a more decentralized, market-oriented and export promotion regime. While significant progress has been made since the economic reform in liberalizing the trade regime, Chinas foreign trade regime still has major inefficiencies. China still largely monopolizes international trade in agricultural products.
Domestic Support of Agriculture
Fiscal and financial policies
Government fiscal expenditure on agriculture has been consistent higher than fiscal revenue from agricultural tax and other fees collected from agriculture (Huang, 1999). However, this fiscal revenue from agriculture based on explicit tax and fees is only small portion of the total agricultural capital contribution to the industry and to the urban sector. A significant capital outflow from agriculture to industry occurred in the last 2 decades through financial system, particularly through Rural Credit Cooperatives (Huang and Ma, 1998). After accounted for agricultural explicit tax through government procurement system, they show that China accumulated a total amount of about 313 billion yuan (at 1985 price) from agricultural sector for the national industrialization in 1978-96, and about 563 billion yuan from the rural sector for the urban economy in the same period. Moreover, the shifting capitals from the agriculture to the industry, and from the rural sector to the urban have shown an increasing trend since the reform initiated in the late 1970s.
Agricultural Protection
Price and market reforms are key components of Chinas development policy shift from a socialist to a market-oriented economy. The price and market reforms initiated in the late 1970's were aimed at raising farm level prices and gradually liberalizing the market. These reforms included increases in quota and above quota prices, reduction in quota levels, introduction of above quota bonuses for cotton, tobacco, and other cash crops, negotiated procurement of surplus production of grains, oils, and most other commodities, and flexibility in marketing of surplus production of all categories of agricultural products privately.
Table 4 shows the estimates of nominal and real protection rates based on various producers' prices from 1978 to 1998 for selected agricultural commodities. Several observations may be made from Table 4. The quota prices consistently represented a disprotection to farmers. The introduction of negotiated procurement significantly reduced the disprotection from government procurement operations. Not surprisingly, the most heavily taxed commodities are the exportable rice. Wheat, importable commodity, is more favored. Aside from the lower quota price NPR for rice, the proportion of grain procurement at the higher negotiated price is typically higher for corn and soybeans. It is also worth to note that the NPRs for wheat and maize at free market prices have been about 20-25 percent since the mid-1990s.
In sum, despite substantial efforts to liberalize the price and market structure of the agricultural sector, most major agricultural commodities continue to be heavily penalized by commodity specific policies. When the impact of the overvaluation of the domestic currency due to the trade protection system is considered, the agricultural incentives would even be more undervalued. These distortions in price incentives depress agricultural production and redistributes income from farmers to urban consumers and the agro-processing sector.
III. Patterns of Agricultural Trade
Trends of Total and Agricultural Trade
One of the most significant features of Chinas open door policy and the shifting trade regimes is the remarkable expansion of Chinas international trade. The average annual export rose from US$ 22.16 billion in 1980-84 to US$160.84 billion in 1995-97, increased more than 7 times or with an annual growth rate of 14.6% (Huang an Chen, 1999b). Although the import also increased significantly, increased more than 6 times during the same period, the annual growth rate of the import (12.2%) was lower than the export growth. This led China moving from a trade deficit in 1980s to a significant trade surplus in 1990s. China has enjoyed annual trade surplus of about US$ 23 billion since the mid-1990s. Currently, China has about US$ 140 billion foreign exchange reserve (SSB, 1999).
Because of the fast growth of international trade, China has greatly improved its position and increased its share in the world trade. Chinas exports ranked only the 26th place in 1980 , however, it ranked the 11th in 1996 among the world trading nations, and in 1997 China was the 10th largest trading nation in the world. In the same time, Chinas share in the world total trade also increased, for example, its export share increased from 0.9% in 1980 to 2.9% in 1996.
Agricultural trade had been an important contributor to Chinas foreign trade. However, because of the declining trend of agriculture in Chinas economy, the importance of agricultural trade in Chinas total trade has been declining since 1980 and particularly since the early 1990s. The share of agricultural trade in Chinas total trade was 21% in 1980-84 and declined to 8.7% only in 1995-97 (Table 5). The shares of agricultural export and import in Chinas total export and import presented the same declining trend.
Despite the share of agricultural trade in Chinas total trade has declined, however, Chinas agricultural trade has also increased during the past two decades but with a slower growth rate as compared to the much faster growth rate of Chinas overall foreign trade. As shown in Table 11, the annual Chinas agricultural trade value increased from US$9,112.8 million in 1980-84 to US$25,772 billion in 1995-97, with an annual growth rate of 6.0%. During the same period, the annual growth rate of agricultural export was 8.0%. Chinas agricultural trade balance has been in a surplus position since 1983. Annual agriculture trade surplus reached about US$ 4-6 billion in 1990s.
In terms of the degree of "openness" of Chinas agricultural sector, as shown in Table 2, Chinas agricultural sector has been relatively less open to the world economy than the rest of Chinas economy. However, the ratio of agricultural trade to agricultural GDP has increased from 10.3% in 1980 to 14.9% in 1997, indicating that while the sectors participating rate in the world market is relative low, Chinas agricultural sector has been increasing its participation in the world agricultural market since 1980s. Comparing agricultural export and import, from 1980 to 1997 the ratio of agricultural export to agricultural GDP increased from 4.6% to 9.1%, while the ratio of agricultural import to agricultural GDP has barely changed. This may suggest that Chinas increasing participation in the world agricultural market is mainly in its agricultural export sector, a reflection of moving from import-substitution strategy to a more export promoting regime.
The Changing Structure of Chinas Agricultural Trade
For the purpose of analysis, we grouped the agricultural trade data in two ways. First, in the analysis of the composition of Chinas agricultural trade, we divide the agricultural trade data into four categories based on the nature of commodities, namely grains and edible vegetable oils, horticultural products, animal products and other agricultural products. Second, in the analysis of the patterns of Chinas agricultural trade, we grouped the agricultural trade data into three categories based on the factor intensity of production, namely land intensive agricultural products, labor intensive agricultural products, and labor/capital intensive agricultural products.
China has been exporting mainly horticultural and animal products, while importing grains and edible vegetable oils. These patterns of agricultural trade are consistent with Chinas resource endowments.
Tables 6 and 7 present the annual shares of exports and imports of the four commodity groups in Chinas agricultural trade from 1980 to 1997. As the tables show, in terms of exports, the changing trend in the patterns of agricultural exports has occurred since 1985. The shares of horticultural products and particularly the animal products increased steadily and their combined share increased from 57% in 1985 to 75% in 1997. In contrast, the share of grains and edible vegetable oils has declined continuously from 33% in 1985 to 21% in 1997. For import commodities, the changing trend is not as clear as that for exports.
The patterns of Chinas agricultural trade for the commodity groups based the factor intensity are presented in Tables 8 and 9. The results show that Chinas agricultural exports were overwhelmingly dominated by the exports of labor intensive agricultural products and labor/capital intensive agricultural products. Their shares accounted for 47% and 35% of Chinas total agricultural exports, respectively in the period of 1980-97, and have presented an increasing trend since the mid-1980s. While the exports of land intensive agricultural products accounted for only 19% and the share of their export declined in the same period.
In terms of imports, Chinas agricultural imports were dominated by the imports of land intensive agricultural products, accounting for 59% of Chinas total agricultural imports. While the imports of labor intensive agricultural products and labor/capital intensive agricultural products accounted for only 20% and 21% of Chinas total agricultural imports, respectively. Similar to the results presented in Table 7, no clear trend was found in the imported commodities.
In sum, the above discussion of the patterns of Chinas agricultural trade has revealed two main points. First, in terms of the aggregate level, the pattern of Chinas agricultural trade is consistent with Chinas domestic resource endowments. China was a net exporter of labor intensive and labor/capital intensive agricultural products, like horticultural products, animal products and processed agricultural products, and a net importer of land intensive agricultural products, like grains, cotton, and edible vegetable oils. Second, in terms of the changing trend, there are evidence and reasons to argue that over the past two decades the patterns of Chinas agricultural trade have been moving more closely towards playing its comparative advantage especially in exporting more labor intensive and labor/capital intensive agricultural products.
IV. Impacts of Trade Liberalization on Chinas Agriculture
A Brief Discussion of the Model
In order to evaluate the impacts of trade liberalization on Chinas agriculture in the future, we apply an existing CCAP's Agricultural Policy Simulation and Projection Model (CAPSiM). CAPSiM was developed out of need to have a framework for analyzing policies affecting agriculture in general, polices related to the macro-economy, trade, and policies directed to agricultural commodities in particular. CAPSiM is a partial equilibrium model, or sector-wise general equilibrium model (considering all cross price impacts for both demand and supply equations). It is the first most comprehensive model for China s food demand, supply and trade analysis. Most of the elasticities and parameters used in the CAPSiM are estimated econometrically with imposition of theoretically constraints. In the projection or policy simulation, prices can be determined endogenously or exogenously. CAPSiM explicitly accounts for urbanization and market development (demand side), technology, agricultural investment, environmental trends and competition for labor and land use (supply side), as well as the price responses of both demand and supply.
The main purpose of the CAPSiM is to project key agricultural variables in the short-term as well as in the long run in response to the changes of the exogenous shocks to the economy. It is also designed for analyzing the likely impacts of specific policies on key variables such as crop sown area, yield, production, prices, consumption, commodity demand and its components (food, feed and other use), stock, and export and import for each agricultural commodity. Details of the model description could be found in Huang and Rozelle (1998), and Huang and Chen (1999b).
Defining Projection Scenarios
All simulations begin with the year of 1994-1996, the base period. Base period data on production and utilization are three-year averages centered on 1995.
Baseline Scenario
Income growth and population growth will remain an important determinant of food balance in the future. Population growth peaked in China in the late 1960s and early 1970s. Since then, fertility rates and the natural rate of population growth have begun to fall. Relying on the United Nation's demographic predictions, the growth rate during 1996-2000, is assumed to be 1.11 percent per annum. This annual rate falls during the next 5 years to 0.88 percent, a level that is considerably under the world's projected growth rate (1.70-1.80 percent), but above recent projections by Chinas demographers. The shares of urban population will rise from 28 percent in the base year to 31 percent by 2000 and to 35 percent in 2005, and 46% in 2020.
Baseline per capita income growth rate is forecast to average about 4 percent in the rural sector and 4.5 percent in the urban sector. The growth rates in the late 1980s and early 1990s were substantially above this level in the urban economy (around 6-7 percent), and significantly below this in rural areas (less than 1 percent per year between 1985 and 1992). But in recent years the overheated urban growth has slowed, and since 1991, the rural economy has begun to pull out of its recession, growing at 4 percent per year.
The agricultural commodity prices under baseline are endogenously determined and are generated from the simulations using CAPSiM model, assuming the current trade policy (tariff levels and non-tariff restrictions) remained.
Supply will respond most to prices, new technology and irrigation investment. The fertilizer price is assumed to be constant in the projection period. But the opportunity costs of land for crop production and labor for the whole agricultural sector are assumed to grow 1 percent and 2 percent, respectively, in 1996-2005.
Technological change has significantly contributed to China's agricultural growth in the past (Huang and Rozelle, 1996; Fan and Pardey, 1997). However, annual expenditures on research declined from 1985 to 1990, and irrigation expenditures dropped from 1975 to 1985. Because of lags, these early investment dips will keep baseline projections of investment growth below historic rates in the early projection period. The recent recovery in research and irrigation investments, together with the experience of other Asian countries and China's commitment to a strong domestic grain economy, leads to the expectation that China will sustain its recent upturn in investment funding over the long run. The annual growth rates of research and irrigation expenditure are assumed to be 4.0 percent and 3.5 percent respectively in the future. Erosion and salinization are expected to continue to increase at a steady but slow pace.
Alternative Scenarios: Free Trade and Productivity Enhancement Growth Scenarios
While China is not a WTO member, it is likely that China will join WTO soon given the progress that has made in recent various WTOs negotiations. On the other hand, a preside formulation for a scenario that China will fit in after its join WHO is difficult as the final agreement has not been reached despite after 13 years negotiations. In order to have a better understanding of the impacts of Chinas accession to the WTO on Chinas domestic agricultural market and trade, we assume that China will continue liberalizing its agricultural sector and reach a free trade environment for the most agricultural commodities by the year of 2005. Specifically, the free trade scenario in this study assumes 14 major agricultural products (7 grain products including rice, wheat, maize, soybean, sweet potato, potato and other grains, and 7 animal products including pork, beef, mutton, poultry, egg, milk and fish) will gradually reduce its tariff level, export subsidies, and trade barriers after 2000, and will reach a zero tariff, completely phase out non-tariff trade barriers by the year 2005. This represents a maximum impact of trade liberalization on Chinas agriculture. The actual impact of trade liberalization and Chinas joining WTO will lay between the simulation results of the baseline scenario and the free trade scenario.
Under the free trade scenario, both import tariff and trade barriers for agricultural inputs such as fertilizer and pesticide will also be reduced and eventually be phased out in 2005, therefore the fertilizer and pesticide prices are assumed to decline by 20 percent from 2000 to 2005. All other assumptions are the same as those defined in the baseline scenario.
It is worth to note that the CAPSiM model is a country model. The impacts of Chinas trade liberalization on the world market prices are not examined given the nature of the model. It is expected that the increase in the import of feed grain under the free trade scenario will raise the international market prices of feed, particular maize price. Similarly, as we will see from the simulation results presented in the next section, trade liberalization will increase Chinas pork and poultry export. Therefore, we are expecting the world pork and poultry prices will decline with the extent of Chinas trade liberalization.
In order to estimate the impacts of the world agricultural price changes (due to Chinas trade liberalization) on Chinas agricultural trade, we simulate the free trade scenario in 2 stages. In the first stage, the world prices of all agricultural products are assumed to be constant in the real term in 2000-2005. The results from the first stage on Chinas imports and exports of various agricultural commodities then are used as the information to adjust the possible changes in the world market. In the second stage, the model will simulate with the changes in the world prices. This procedure could be repeated until the marginal changes from additional round of simulation in the imports or exports of agricultural commodities are minimal.
In order to provide a long term prospects on Chinas food security under a free trade regime, we project Chinas food supply, demand and trade toward 2020 under a free trade scenario without and with the progressive improvement in agricultural productivity enhancement investment. The later assumes that the annual growth rate of agricultural research expenditure will rise from 4 percent (baseline assumption) to 6 percent.
Table 11 presents the price differences of the selected agricultural products in Chinas domestic markets under the baseline scenario and the free trade scenario from 2000 to 2005 projected by the CAPSiM.
Under the baseline scenario, the increases in the domestic production of rice, wheat, other grains, and the most of animal products will nearly meet the increase in the domestic demand for these commodities, the changes in their trades over the period of 2000-2005 will be marginal (see next sub-section). Therefore the changes in the domestic prices (real term in 1995 price) of most these commodities will range only from 1 percent to 2 percent in 2000-2005 (Table 11). This implies that Chinas domestic grain prices, except the price of rice, will continue to be higher than the grain prices in the world market from 2000 to 2005. On the other hand, the animal products, mainly livestock sector will continue to be heavily taxed. Furthermore, the differences between grain prices in Chinas domestic and the world markets will increase from 2000 to 2005. In particular, the price of maize, wheat and soybean in Chinas domestic market will far exceed the prices in the world market.
In contrast, under the free trade scenario, Chinas domestic grain market prices (except for rice) will decline gradually from 2000 to 2005. The prices of wheat, maize and soybean in Chinas domestic market will decline significantly, ranging from 10 percent to 20 percent, in 2000-2005.
Table 20 also shows the price differences between the baseline and the free trade scenarios. The results indicate that the producers of crops (except for rice) will loss their income from the farming activities under the free trade scenario (compared to the baseline scenario) as the most crop product prices decline with the trade liberalization. While the most of animal product (except for beef, mutton, and milk) producers, particularly the farmers in raising hog and poultry, will benefit from the trade liberalization. The prices of the pork, poultry, egg, and fish will be about 5 percent to 15 percent higher than those under the baseline scenario in 2005.
Among various grains, rice is the only commodity, its price rise with the trade liberalization. The increase price of rice is the results of increase in the rice export and the reduction of rice demand due to the cross-price substitution of other food grains (mainly wheat). Under the free trade scenario, the percentage changes of wheat, maize and soybean prices related to the baseline will be as high as 19.9%, 26.0% and 20.4%, respectively, in 2005 (Table 11).
The impacts of trade liberalization on the prices of sweet potato, potato and other grains in Chinas domestic market are similar. Under the free trade scenario, the prices of these coarse grains will be about 10 percent lower than the prices under baseline scenario in 2005 (Table 11).
Trade liberalization will tend to increase the prices of animal products in Chinas domestic market. Our projection shows that the domestic pork price in the free trade scenario will be about 14% higher than that in the baseline scenario in 2005. Similar positive effects of trade liberalization the domestic prices are found for poultry (10%), egg (4%) and aquatic products (6%). On the other hand, the trade liberalization will significantly decrease the domestic price of milk. The milk price under the free trade regime will decline by more than 20% over the period of 2000-2005.
The decline in the prices of grain with trade liberalization, particularly maize, wheat and soybean will dampen the profitability of grain production, reduce the earnings of the farmers whose incomes are mainly from grain production. While demands for maize, wheat and soybean are expected to rise with the decline in their prices. Grain production growth is expected to be slow down with the increasing liberalization of agricultural trade. In contrast, the increase in the prices of pork and poultry will directly increase the returns of these animal products and, therefore, increase the income of pork and poultry producers. Such a "windfall" income increase to these animal product producers will stimulate their incentives in the production of pork and poultry. Consequently, there will be an expansion in the production of animal products particularly the production of pork and poultry in China after trade liberalization.
The interesting point is that the feed grain consumers are the animal product producers. On the one hand, animal product producers will gain from the increase of animal product prices. On the other hand, animal product producers who are also the feed grain consumers will gain from the decline in the feed grain prices, which will reduce the production costs of their animal products. Consequently, we will expect that there will be not only a large increase in feed grain demand, but also a large expansion in animal product production after trade liberalization.
Tables 21 and 22 present the impacts of the trade liberalization (the difference or percentage difference relative to the baseline) on production, consumption and trade of grains and animal products under the baseline scenario in 2000-2005.
Baseline Scenario
According to the analysis, per capita food grain consumption in China hit its zenith in the late 1990s and falls over the remaining forecast period. The average rural resident will increase slightly food grain consumption through 2005, and urban resident food grain consumption will level off in the projection period. The ebb of per capita food grain demand at the national level occurs at a time when both rural and urban food grain demands do not decline because of the impact of urbanization.
Because of the higher quality of fine grains, total rice and wheat consumption per capita will rise slightly through the year 2000, reflecting their still positive, albeit small, income elasticities, both rural and urban consumers demand higher quantities of rice and wheat. Per capita demand for other food grains, however, falls monotonically over the projection period.
In contrast, per capita demand for red meat is forecast to rise sharply throughout the projection period. Rural demand will grow more slowly than overall demand, but urbanization trends will shift more people into the higher-consuming urban areas (in middle 1990s an urban resident consumed about 60 percent more red meat than his/her rural counterpart). While starting from a lower level, per capita demand for poultry rise proportionally more. The projected rise in meat and poultry product demand will stimulate aggregate feed grain demand.
Baseline projections of the supply of grain show that although Chinas domestic total grain production will increase from 431.68 mmt in 2000 to 463.78 mmt in 2005 with an annual growth rate of 1.44%. The production growth rate fells bellow domestic grain consumption growth rate (1.60%), indicating a widening gap between domestic supply of and demand for grains. The growth rate of grain production in 2000-2005 will be much lower than the growth rates obtained in 1980s and 1990s, an evidence of the impacts of declining the public investment intensity in agricultural R&D since the mid-1980s (Huang et. al., 1998). The grain net imports will rise to nearly 20 mmt in 2005 (Table 12). Despite the increase in the grain import in the period of 2000-2005, grain self-sufficient level will remain as high as 95-96% in the early 21st century.
In the livestock and aquatic sector, the increases in the domestic production nearly match the increases in demand. The annual production growth rates of various animal products will range from 3% to 7% in the period of 2000-2005, the growth rates are equivalent to the growth rates of the demands for these products in the same period (Table 13). The sector will continue to be an exportable one, but the amount of exported livestock products and fish are very small compared to the size of the total domestic production or consumption.
Pork, which accounted for about 70% of meat or nearly 90% of red meat consumption, its demand will rise from 23.20 mmt in 2000 to 27.46 mmt in 2005 with an annual growth rate of 3.43% in 2000-2005 (Table 13). Under the baseline scenario, pork production is also projected to growth at 3.39% annual, a growth rate level close to the demand growth (note: the livestock data used in this paper are significantly different from the data published by the State Statistical Bureau. CAPSiM model uses a complete new set data that correct for over-report of livestock production and under-report of its consumption). The trends of production, consumption and trade of beef and mutton are roughly the same as those for pork.
The poultry and milk are the only two animal products that require import (4-5% of domestic consumption) to meet the increasing demand. Poultry consumption will rise from 6.29 mmt in 2000 to 7.89 mmt in 2005 with an annual growth rate of 4.61%. Because domestic poultry consumption is higher than domestic poultry production in the base year, although the growth rate of poultry production is slightly higher than that of poultry consumption, China still will be a net poultry importer in 2000-2005. The annual import of poultry will be around 0.25 0.29 mmt in 2000-2005. Milk import will present a slightly increasing tread, rising from 0.30 mmt in 2000 to 0.33 mmt tons in 2005, account for 3.4% of the total consumption (Table 13).
Free Trade Scenario
Under free trade scenario, domestic grain price (except for rice) will fall. The fall in the domestic price of grain raises the grain consumption and slowdown the production. Our projection shows that Chinas domestic grain production will fall far behind domestic grain consumption under the free trade scenario. Compared to the baseline scenario, grain deficit between domestic supply and demand will be further enlarged. Chinas net grain imports will increase to 59.61 mmt in 2005 (Table 12, a level representing about 12% of the total grain consumption in China. Comparing with the baseline scenario, Chinas domestic grain production will decline by 10.63 mmt (or 2.3%), while Chinas domestic grain consumption will increase by 29.28 mmt (or 6.0%) in 2005.
The most serious impacts of trade liberalization on grains are maize, and then followed by wheat and soybean. Under the free trade scenario, Chinas domestic maize production will fall far behind maize consumption. The production will grow annually by 0.69% only, while the consumption will grow by 5.91% as a results of the decline in maize price and surging feed demand for livestock production expansion after trade liberalization. Consequently, the imports of maize will increase dramatically from less than 2 mmt in 2000 to 39.31 mmt (nearly one quarter of maize consumption in China) in 2005. China would likely be the world largest importer of maize in the coming years if the sector would be completely liberalized. Comparing with the baseline projections, as shown in Table 21, the net impacts of trade liberalization on the annual maize production, consumption, and trade will be 5.38 mmt, 11.39 mmt, and 16.76 mmt, respectively, for the average of 2000-2005. In the year of 2005 when the completed trade liberalization reached, the net impacts of trade liberalization (relative to baseline) on the maize production, consumption, and trade will reach the highest levels as 10.42 mmt (or a reduction of 7.8%), 20.21 mmt (or an increase of 14.2%), and 30.62 mmt (or an increase of 3.52 times), respectively.
Although wheat is food grain and the food grain consumption response to the price change is weaker than that of feed grains, the impact of trade liberalization on wheat is also substantial. From 2000 to 2005, the annual growth rate of wheat production will fall from 1.29% in the baseline to 0.43% in the free trade scenario (Table 12). While wheat consumption growth rate will rise from 0.93% in the baseline to 2.06% in the free trade scenario in the same period. Wheat production is projected to be only 110.46 mmt in 2005, 5.06 mmt (or 4.4%) lower than that in the baseline projection. By 2005, the wheat imports will rise sharply from the 11.73 mmt in 2000 to 22.26 mmt in 2005. Comparing with the baseline projections, wheat consumption under the free trade scenario will tend to increase by 7.28 mmt (or 5.8%) in 2005. And the net impacts of the free trade verse baseline scenarios on wheat import will be as high as 12.34 mmt (rise from 9.92 mmt to 22.26 mmt) in 2005.
The soybean is the other grain crop that will be affected significantly by the trade liberalization. By 2005, soybean consumption will reach 16.10 mmt (5.4% higher than baseline scenario), about 9% higher than its production (14.79 mmt, or 4.3% lower than the baseline)). Soybean net import will reach more than 1.3 mmt or about 8% of the domestic soybean consumption in 2005.
Rice and other coarse grains (mainly millet, sorghum and barley) are the only crops within grains that will benefit from the trade liberalization. Under the free trade scenario, rice production will rise from 132.52 mmt in 2000 to 144.65 mmt in 2005 with an annual growth rate of 1.77% (compared to the baseline of 0.89% in Table 12). The higher rate of production growth is the results of the rise in rice price and the decline in the prices of inputs such as fertilizer and pesticide under the free trade scenario. Meantime, the increase in the rice price reduces the annual rice consumption growth rate from 0.8% in the baseline to only 0.55% in the period of 2000-2005. Combined impacts of production and consumption imply that the impact of trade liberalization on rice export is substantial (7.12 mmt in 2005).
The impacts of trade liberalization on Chinas animal sector are also significant. But in contrast to the grain sector, the trade liberalization will raise domestic prices of pork and poultry substantially, and a moderate rise in the prices of egg and fish. The increase in the prices of these major animal products and a decrease in the feed price resulting from the trade liberalization will stimulate the domestic production of these products on the one hand, and dampen their consumption on the other hand. Livestock and fish product exports will expand considerable (Table 13).
For example, under the free trade scenario, Chinas domestic pork production will increase from 23.12 mmt in 2000 to 25.73 mmt in 2005 (Table 13), with an annual growth rate of 6.33% (3.39% in under the baseline scenario). While at the same time pork consumption annual growth rate will decline from 2.43% in the baseline to 2.16% in 2000-2005. The impacts on the pork export will reach 6.0 mmt in 2005.
A similar large impact of the trade liberalization is found for the production, consumption and trade of both poultry and fish simply because of the changes in their poultry prices. The only product that will be significantly and adversely affected by the trade liberalization is milk. About one quarter of the milk consumption will have to import from the world market after 2005, compared to about 3% only of imported milk only in the baseline scenario.
Food security has been and will continue to be one of the central goals of Chinas policy. While food security has many dimensions, one of the targets that was set by Chinese government recently is to achieve grain self-sufficiency level at or above 95% in the future. Although this level of grain self-sufficiency has been widely debated since it set up, any changes including the trade liberalization that could result in the grain self-sufficiency level in the long term far bellow 95% would be hardly adopted by the current government if there is no alternative solutions available.
Table 14 presents Chinas grain self-sufficiency rates under three scenarios for the period of 1995-2020. The third scenario assumes that the growth rate of agricultural research expenditure in the real term raises from 4% (the assumption use in the other scenarios) to 6% during the entire period of the projection.
Several interesting points could be derived from the results presented in Table 23. First, under the baseline scenario, while the grain self-sufficiency rate will decline over time (from 98.1% in the 1994-96 to about 96% in the most years of the next two decades), China will be able to achieve one of the major components of its food security (grain self-sufficiency) target in the future. Only grain that will fell its self-sufficiency level bellow 95% in the long term is maize. Maize self-sufficiency rate will decline significantly from 101.4% in 1994-96 to 93.9% in 2005 and further down to less than 90% in 2020.
Second, although the baseline scenario or the policies embodied in the baseline assumptions would ensure the high level of grain self-sufficiency, the costs related to this scenario should not be underestimated. All grain prices except rice in domestic markets will considerably exceed the prices in the international markets. For example, maize, wheat and soybean domestic prices will exceed international prices by about 26%, 20% and 21% in 2005, respectively, and the gap between the domestic and international prices will enlarge notably after 2005, particular maize price. Maize price will reach as high as wheat price by 2020. Whether government budget and consumers can sustain such a high level of grain price protection policy and how this will affect on the livestock production and export are the issues that needs to be considered.
Third, the completed trade liberalization (the free trade scenario) will obviously challenge the current food security goal defined by the government. Chinas grain self-sufficiency rate will decline rapidly from 98% in the mid-1990s to 88.4% in 2005 (Table 14), a level is hardly accepted by the current government. Although the grain self-sufficiency rate will rise gradually after 2005, there will be still about 8% of domestic grain demand that needs to be met by the imported source in 2020. However, it is worth to note that this is an extreme case (the free trade regime), representing a maximum impact of the trade liberalization on Chinas grain economy. The actual impacts of Chinas joining the WTO will be lower than the results from this free trade scenario.
Fourth, the most effective policy that could improve Chinas food security and raise grain self-sufficiency level in the long term is to increase the agricultural productivity enhancement investment such as agricultural R&D, rural infrastructure and water control (i.e., irrigation). For example, Table 23 shows that China could achieve its grain self-sufficiency target in the long term (after 2015) under the free trade regime if the annual growth rate in agricultural research investment raises from 4% to 6%.
Finally, the shocks of the trade liberalization on Chinas grains differ largely between food and feed grains. Maize will be the major imported grain and used in producing exportable livestock products. Therefore, it is not maize, but rice and wheat their domestic productions and self-sufficiency have directly and the most important impacts on food and, particular grain, security (food grain self-sufficiency) in China. If the food grain self-sufficiency concept could replace the total grain self-sufficiency and be adopted in China, China will achieve its 95% food grain self-sufficient level even under a completely liberalized market in the future (Table 14).
V. Conclusions and Policy Implications
Reform and trade liberalization in China's external sector, because of its strategic role in the economy, has proceeded gradually. Gradual trade liberalization as the reforms in the other sectors of China's economy has its logic. In the initial stage, reformers only implemented measures that provided incentives to sets of corporations and institutions. As the experience gained from the reform grows and the objectives of trade could be achieved through alternative settings of institutions and policies, trade liberalization has been processed smoothly since the late 1980s. Understanding the process will enhance the discussion about China's international trade and help the reader to put into perspective what leaders have done so far, what else they may be intending to do, and why or why they have not gone faster or further.
In the past 20 years, this study shows that the highly centralized and monopolized foreign trade operation system has been gradually reformed, decentralized, and commercialized through granting trade rights to more trade corporations and reducing government direct administrative intervention.
Trade regime has also been gradually moving from import substitution system to a more export-oriented system. Moving toward a more market-oriented trade system is evidenced from various aspects of China's trade policies and trade patterns. The centralized trade management and operation system was first replaced by the foreign trade contract responsibility system, and then was further replaced by taxing system; the foreign exchange retention system was abolished and replaced by foreign exchange bank settlement system; a single managed floating foreign exchange system was introduced in 1994; government export subsidies were phased out; and the financial system related to foreign trade was adjusted to meet the reformed trade system.
Foreign exchange control, though still highly intervened, has been relaxed significantly since the late 1980s by introducing foreign exchange retention system and establishing foreign exchange swap center in the early reform period, and the two-tier exchange rate was consolidated in December 1993. RMB became convertible on the current account at the end of 1996. While tariffs now are still high compared to the existing WTO's member countries and some non-tariff measures are commonly applied to "strategic products" such as agricultural and food products, foreign trade control in China has also significantly liberalized since the early 1990s. Chinas average tariffs reduced from 47.2% in 1991 to 17% in 1998. Apart from these, China has actively participated in the consultations on the tariff-related actions for early voluntary sectoral liberalization.
During the 1980s China extensively used quotas and licensing to control its foreign trade. However, since the early 1990s China has progressively and drastically reduced the number of items subject to export and import quotas and licensing administration. The products subject to quota, licensing and other import control measures accounted for only 5% of the total import tariff lines in 1998.
In sum, through nearly 20 years reform, Chinas foreign trade regime has gradually changed from a highly centralized, planned and import substitution regime to a more decentralized, market-oriented and export promotion regime. While significant progress has been made since the economic reform in liberalizing the trade regime, Chinas foreign trade regime still has major inefficiencies. China still largely monopolizes international trade in agricultural products.
The reforms of the economy have significantly impacted on the structure of the economy. Even a more rapid growth and the trade pattern changes are recorded for Chinas external sector. Because Chinas overall trade growth has been much faster than that of agricultural trade, the importance of agricultural trade in Chinas total trade has been declining considerably since 1980 and particularly since the early 1990s. Within various agricultural commodity trades, this study reveals two main points. First, the patterns of Chinas agricultural trade were consistent with Chinas domestic resource endowments during the reform period. China was a net exporter of labor intensive and labor/capital intensive agricultural products, like horticultural products, animal products and processed agricultural products, and was a net importer of land intensive agricultural products, like grains, cotton, and edible vegetable oils. Second, the study shows that since 1985 the patterns of Chinas agricultural trade, particularly the patterns of agricultural exports, have been gradually moving more closely towards reflecting Chinas resource endowments.
However, this study also reveal that the room for the further liberalization exists in terms of tariff reduction, limiting non-tariff measures to control agricultural imports, further commercialization of state trading, and the efficiency of the foreign trade management. In deed, China has decided to take a further trade liberalization in the coming years. This is evidenced in the recent Joint China-US Statement signed by China Premier Zhu Rongji and US President William Jefferson Clinton on the Status of Negotiation on China's accession to the World Trade Organization in April 1999.
With the further trade liberalization and adjusting China trade regime consistent with joining WTO, it is expected that China will face great challenges in maintaining its current food self-sufficiency, a central agricultural policy that has been a top priority in setting China's all agricultural and agriculture related policies since the founding of the People's Republic of China in 1949.
Our simulation results on the trade liberalization conclude that the producers of most crops (except for rice and horticulture) will loss their income from the farming activities not only because of the decline in the price the farmer will received, but also the reduction in the production. While the most of animal product (except for beef, mutton, and milk) producers, particularly the farmers in raising hog and poultry, will benefit from the trade liberalization as the increase in the export demand rises the livestock price and increase in the maize import declines in the feed price.
The impacts of trade liberalization on Chinas agriculture are remarkable not only on agricultural price and trade, but also on domestic production and consumption. Under free trade scenario, the fall in the domestic price of grain raises the grain consumption and slowdown the production. Our projection shows that Chinas domestic grain production will fall far behind domestic grain consumption under the free trade scenario. Compared to the baseline scenario, grain deficit between domestic supply and demand will be further enlarged. Chinas net grain imports will increase to about 60 mmt in 2005. Among these, 40 mmt or two third imported grains are maize.
Our study also concludes that maize, the third major crop just bellow rice and wheat, will soon grow over rice and wheat, and become a top crop not only in the quantity of its domestic consumption (demand), but will soon become the number one imported crop in China. China would likely be one of the world largest importers of maize in the coming years if the market will be liberalized.
In contract to many scholars believe, while the trade liberalization will raise wheat import in the short run, the wheat import will be soon declining after the initial shock of the trade liberalization. China will become a nearly self-sufficiency in wheat in the long term (by 2020). On the other hand, China is likely to be one of the major exporters of livestock products in the world. Pork and poultry exports will expand profound with the trade liberalization.
In related to the food security and grain self-sufficient issues, a completely liberalized economy in the short term will challenge the current food security goal defined by the government. Chinas grain self-sufficiency rate will decline rapidly from 98% in the mid-1990s to less than 90% in 2005 if the free trade regime is assumed by the year of 2005. However, it is worth to note that this is an extreme case, representing a maximum impact of the trade liberalization on Chinas grain economy. The actual impacts of Chinas joining the WTO will be lower than the results from this free trade scenario.
When regarding the world food situation, our results suggest that China will neither empty the world grain markets, nor become a major grain exporter. It does seem likely, however, that China will become a more important player in world grain markets as an importer in the coming decades. Both potential exporters outside of China and those charged with managing China's food needs through domestic production and imports need to be ready. Exporting nations--especially those dealing with wheat (in the short run) and maize (in the long run) --will undoubtedly be the beneficiaries of these trends.
If China's policy makers believe the projected level of imports are too high (either politically or because they see some other physical or economic constraint), investment strategies need to be revised in the near future. In the long term, the most effective policy that could improve Chinas food security and raise grain self-sufficiency level is to increase the agricultural productivity enhancement investment, particular agricultural R&D. If these policies are formulated properly, China could achieve its grain self-sufficiency target in the second decade of the next century even the grain market will be completely liberalized in 2000-2005.
China should allow a greater role for the market to determine trade patterns in order to reap comparative advantage gains. This would probably mean increased overall agricultural trade and a shift towards importing more land intensive agricultural products and exporting more labor intensive agricultural products. Policy steps to achieve comparative advantage gains might include removing implicit taxes on farmers and reforming domestic grain pricing and marketing system.
References
Development Research Center, (1998) the Global and Domestic Impact of China Joining the World Trade Organization, A Project Report, Development Research Center, the State Council, China
Editorial Board of the Almanac of Chinas Foreign Economic Relations and Trade,
Fan, S, and P. Pardey. "Research Productivity and Output Growth in Chinese Agriculture," Journal of Development Economics, Vol.53(1997):115-137.
Foreign Investment Administration of the Ministry of Foreign Trade and Economic
Huang, J. (1998), "The Impact of Joining the WTO on Chinas Grain Market," International Trade, no.20(1998):10-13..
Huang, J. and C. Chen, 1999a. Effects of Trade Liberalization on Agriculture in China: Institutional and Structural Aspects. United Nations ESCAP CGPRT Centre, Bogor, Indonesia.
Huang, J. and C. Chen,1999b. Effects of Trade Liberalization on Agriculture in China: Commodity and Local Agricultural Studies, United Nations ESCAP CGPRT Centre, Bogor, Indonesia.
Huang, J., S. Rozelle, and M. Rosegrant. 1998. "Chinas Food Economy to the 21st Century: Supply, Demand and Trade," Economic Development and Cultural Change, (forthcoming).
Huang, J., S. Rozelle and M. Rosegrant. 1997. "Public Investment, Technological Change and Reform: A Comprehensive Accounting of Chinese Agricultural Growth," Working Paper, Food Research Institute, Stanford University.
Huang, J. and S. Rozelle. 1996. "Technological Change: The Re-Discovery of the Engine of Productivity Growth in China's Rice Economy," Journal of Development Economics, Vol.49(1996):337-369.
Huang, J. (1998), "The Impact of Joining the WTO on Chinas Grain Market," International Trade, no.20(1998):10-13..
Huang, J. (1999), "Agricultural Policy and Food Security in China", in Food and
Lardy, N.R. Foreign Trade and Economic Reform in China 1978-90. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1992.
Lardy, N.R. (1995) "The Role of Foreign Trade and Investment in China's Economic Transition," The China Quarterly, No.144, December, pp1065-1082.
Ministry of Foreign Trade and Economic Cooperation (1998), "Individual Action Plan
Naughton, B. (1996). "China's Dual Trading Regimes: Implications for Growth and Reform", A Paper Presented at An International Economics Association Roundtable Conference on International trade Policy and the Pacific Rim, Sydney, 15-17 July 1996.
State Statistical Bureau, various issues of Zhongguo Tongji Nianjian [China Statistical
Yearbook], Zhongguo Tongji Chubanshe, Beijing.
State Statistical Bureau, Zhongguo Duiwai Jingji Tongji Nianjian [China
United Nations (1994), World Investment Report 1994: Transnational Corporations,
Wang, Z. (1997), "The Impact of China and Taiwan joining the World Trade
World Bank (1997), "China Engaged: Integration with the Global Economy" in
China 2020, The World Bank, Washington D.C.
Table 1. Annual Growth Rates (%) of Chinas Economy, 1970-97
Pre-reform 1970-78 |
Reform period |
|||
1979-84 |
1985-95 |
1996-97 |
||
Gross domestic products | 4.9 |
8.5 |
9.7 |
9.2 |
Agriculture | 2.7 |
7.1 |
4.0 |
4.3 |
Industry | 6.8 |
8.2 |
12.8 |
11.4 |
Service | na |
11.6 |
9.7 |
8.0 |
Foreign trade | 20.5 |
14.3 |
15.2 |
7.6 |
Import | 21.7 |
12.7 |
13.4 |
10.8 |
Export | 19.4 |
15.9 |
17.2 |
3.8 |
Population | 1.8 |
1.4 |
1.37 |
1.03 |
GDP per capita | 3.1 |
7.1 |
8.3 |
8.2 |
Source: State Statistical Bureau, China Statistical Yearbook, various issues.
Table 2. Foreign trade to GDP ratios (%) in China, 1980-97.
Year |
Total trade to national GDP |
Agricultural trade to agricultural GDP |
Total export to national GDP |
Total import to national GDP |
Agricultural export to agricultural GDP |
Agricultural import to agricultural GDP |
1980 |
12.7 |
10.3 |
6.0 |
6.7 |
4.6 |
5.6 |
1985 |
22.8 |
9.6 |
9.0 |
13.8 |
6.7 |
2.8 |
1990 |
29.8 |
14.5 |
16.0 |
13.8 |
9.1 |
5.4 |
1995 |
40.1 |
18.6 |
21.3 |
18.9 |
10.2 |
8.4 |
1997 |
36.0 |
14.9 |
20.3 |
15.8 |
9.1 |
5.8 |
Table 3. Chinas Simple Average Applied Tariff Rate (%), 1998-2000.
Item | 1998 simple average applied tariff rate |
2000 simple average applied tariff rate |
Agricultural products (excluding fish products) | 23.6 |
32 |
Fish and fish products | 20.0 |
29 |
Petroleum oils | 7.9 |
5 |
Wood, pulp, paper and furniture | 14.5 |
17 |
Textiles and clothing | 27.2 |
22 |
Leather, rubber, footwear and travel goods | 17.0 |
20 |
Metals | 10.1 |
9 |
Chemical and photographic supplies | 11.9 |
10 |
Transport equipment | 26.8 |
25 |
Non-electric machinery | 14.2 |
11 |
Electric machinery | 16.8 |
13 |
Mineral products, precious stones and metals | 11.5 |
11 |
Other manufactured goods | 16.8 |
13 |
All goods | 17.0 |
15 |
1978-79 |
1980-84 |
1985-89 |
1990-94 |
1995-98a |
|
Evaluated at the official exchange rate |
|||||
Quota procurement prices | |||||
Rice | -42 |
-43 |
-30 |
-37 |
-18 |
Wheat | 15 |
-3 |
4 |
-14 |
-9 |
Maize | 12 |
-15 |
-13 |
-35 |
-2 |
Soybean | 2 |
13 |
-13 |
-32 |
-26 |
Negotiated procurement prices | |||||
Rice | -6 |
2 |
-5 |
-16 |
-7 |
Wheat | 72 |
50 |
34 |
14 |
0 |
Maize | 65 |
28 |
12 |
-7 |
8 |
Soybean | 22 |
25 |
15 |
7 |
2 |
Market retail price | |||||
Rice | 38 |
19 |
14 |
-2 |
4 |
Wheat | 89 |
58 |
52 |
26 |
20 |
Maize | 92 |
46 |
37 |
12 |
25 |
Soybean | 40 |
44 |
39 |
26 |
13 |
Procurement prices | |||||
Rapeseed | 11 |
22 |
-1 |
8 |
0 |
Cotton | 0 |
4 |
-19 |
-26 |
-5 |
Sugarcane | na |
na |
na |
-27 |
-15 |
Sugarbeet | na |
na |
na |
-11 |
3 |
Evaluated at the real exchange rate |
|||||
Quota procurement prices | |||||
Rice | -73 |
-73 |
-69 |
-70 |
-41 |
Wheat | -46 |
-54 |
-54 |
-59 |
-35 |
Maize | -48 |
-60 |
-61 |
-69 |
-29 |
Soybean | -52 |
-47 |
-61 |
-67 |
-48 |
Negotiated procurement prices | |||||
Rice | -56 |
-52 |
-58 |
-60 |
-34 |
Wheat | -20 |
-30 |
-42 |
-46 |
-29 |
Maize | -23 |
-40 |
-48 |
-55 |
-23 |
Soybean | -43 |
-41 |
-49 |
-49 |
-28 |
Market retail price | |||||
Rice | -36 |
-44 |
-50 |
-53 |
-26 |
Wheat | -12 |
-26 |
-34 |
-39 |
-14 |
Maize | -10 |
-32 |
-40 |
-46 |
-10 |
Soybean | -34 |
-32 |
-38 |
-40 |
-20 |
Procurement prices | |||||
Rapeseed | -48 |
-43 |
-56 |
-48 |
-31 |
Cotton | -53 |
-51 |
-63 |
-65 |
-35 |
Sugarcane | na |
na |
na |
-64 |
-42 |
Sugarbeet | na |
na |
na |
-56 |
-29 |
Note: Chinas import or export unit values are used as border prices except in the case of maize, for which we used U.S. Gulf Port prices time 1.10 as the border price. No quality adjustments are made for all products.
Table 5. Annual Agricultural Trade Indicators in China, 1980-97.
Period | Agri. trade (million US$) |
Agri. share in total trade (%) |
Agri. export (million US$) |
Agri. share in total export (%) |
Agri. import (million US$) |
Agri. share in total import (%) |
Agri. trade balance (million US$) |
80-84 | 9113 |
21.0 |
4368 |
19.8 |
4745 |
22.4 |
-378 |
85-89 | 11906 |
13.4 |
7664 |
19.7 |
4243 |
8.5 |
3421 |
90-94 | 17048 |
10.4 |
11625 |
13.7 |
5423 |
7.0 |
6201 |
95-97 | 25772 |
8.7 |
14908 |
9.3 |
10864 |
7.9 |
4044 |
Annual growth rate (%) | 6.0 |
8.0 |
3.9 |
Table 10 Trade Balance of Agricultural Commodities in China (US$ Million), 1980-97.
Annual Average |
||||||
1980-84 |
1985-89 |
1990-94 |
1995-97 |
1980-97 |
Total |
|
Total Agri. Imports | -378 |
3421 |
6201 |
4044 |
3242 |
58356 |
Grain & Edible Vegetable Oils | -1965 |
-218 |
-147 |
-3789 |
-1279 |
-23016 |
Cereals | -2287 |
-913 |
-337 |
-1863 |
-1293 |
-23272 |
Cereal products & animal feed | 87 |
369 |
312 |
-468 |
136 |
2439 |
Oil seeds | 225 |
578 |
553 |
34 |
382 |
6878 |
Edible vegetable oils | 10 |
-253 |
-675 |
-1491 |
-503 |
-9061 |
Horticultural Products | 1619 |
2344 |
3699 |
4712 |
2914 |
52446 |
Vegetables and fruits | 764 |
1223 |
2054 |
2850 |
1598 |
28756 |
Coffee and tea | 296 |
414 |
455 |
486 |
405 |
7284 |
Tobacco | -62 |
-136 |
304 |
521 |
116 |
2092 |
Raw silk | 233 |
295 |
318 |
272 |
280 |
5047 |
Other horticultural products a | 388 |
547 |
568 |
583 |
515 |
9267 |
Animal Products | 975 |
1051 |
2566 |
4313 |
1995 |
35904 |
Live animals | 355 |
340 |
435 |
448 |
388 |
6990 |
Meat products | 424 |
517 |
896 |
2206 |
878 |
15803 |
Dairy and egg products | 50 |
11 |
42 |
111 |
47 |
845 |
Seafood products | 316 |
629 |
1100 |
1323 |
789 |
14193 |
Raw wool | -159 |
-476 |
-277 |
-564 |
-347 |
-6249 |
Other animal products b | -10 |
31 |
370 |
789 |
240 |
4322 |
Other Agri. Products | -1007 |
245 |
82 |
-1193 |
-388 |
-6978 |
Sugar | -299 |
-260 |
131 |
-281 |
-166 |
-2982 |
Beverages | 43 |
88 |
243 |
369 |
165 |
2978 |
Raw cotton | -752 |
416 |
-291 |
-1280 |
-387 |
-6974 |
Source: Huang and Chen, 1999a.
Table 11. Impacts of trade liberalization on agricultural commodity prices in China (the free trade vs baseline scenarios), 2000-2005 | ||||||
Price in 2005 (yuan/ton in 1995 price) |
Price change in 2000-2005 (%) |
Percentage price difference in 2005 (%) |
||||
Baseline |
Free trade |
Baseline |
Free trade |
Free trade vs baseline |
||
Rice | 2333 |
2415 |
-0.4 |
4.1 |
3.5 |
|
Wheat | 1756 |
1406 |
-1.1 |
-20.2 |
-19.9 |
|
Maize | 1459 |
1080 |
7.5 |
-20.1 |
-26.0 |
|
Soybean | 2918 |
2322 |
0.4 |
-20.2 |
-20.4 |
|
Sweet Potato | 1208 |
1066 |
0.7 |
-9.6 |
-11.8 |
|
Potato | 1211 |
1085 |
-0.4 |
-9.5 |
-10.4 |
|
Other grains | 2290 |
2097 |
-1.8 |
-9.7 |
-8.4 |
|
Pork | 12795 |
14633 |
0.8 |
14.8 |
14.4 |
|
Beef | 14666 |
14518 |
1.8 |
0.0 |
-1.0 |
|
Mutton | 18841 |
18345 |
3.4 |
0.0 |
-2.6 |
|
Poultry | 11643 |
12798 |
0.9 |
10.4 |
9.9 |
|
Egg | 6557 |
6831 |
-3.5 |
0.0 |
4.2 |
|
Milk | 3379 |
2672 |
1.5 |
-20.2 |
-20.9 |
|
Fish | 9032 |
9529 |
-4.8 |
0.0 |
5.5 |
Table 12. Impacts of the trade liberalization (free trade) on grain production, consumption, and trade, 2000-2005. | ||||||||
Baseline |
Free trade scenario |
Free trade vs baseline scenarios |
||||||
Commodity | In the year of 2005 (000 tons) |
Annual growth rate in 2000-05 (%) |
In the year of 2005 (000 tons) |
Annual growth rate in 2000-05 (%) |
Difference in 2005 (000 tons) |
Annual average difference in 2000-05 (000 tons) |
||
Rice | ||||||||
Production | 138908 |
0.89 |
144652 |
1.77 |
5744 |
2419 |
||
Consumption | 139690 |
0.88 |
138313 |
0.55 |
-1377 |
-248 |
||
Net import | 782 |
-6339 |
-7121 |
-2668 |
||||
Wheat | ||||||||
Production | 115519 |
1.29 |
110458 |
0.43 |
-5061 |
-2672 |
||
Consumption | 125440 |
0.93 |
132721 |
2.06 |
7281 |
4059 |
||
Net import | 9921 |
22263 |
12342 |
6731 |
||||
Maize | ||||||||
Production | 133209 |
2.33 |
122793 |
0.69 |
-10416 |
-5375 |
||
Consumption | 141898 |
3.35 |
162105 |
5.91 |
20207 |
11389 |
||
Net import | 8689 |
39312 |
30623 |
16764 |
||||
Soybean | ||||||||
Production | 15459 |
1.37 |
14792 |
0.47 |
-667 |
-331 |
||
Consumption | 15278 |
1.46 |
16102 |
2.41 |
824 |
533 |
||
Net import | -181 |
1310 |
1491 |
865 |
||||
Sweet potato | ||||||||
Production | 25712 |
1.33 |
25502 |
1.26 |
-210 |
-233 |
||
Consumption | 25599 |
1.34 |
26872 |
2.17 |
1273 |
792 |
||
Net import | -113 |
1370 |
1483 |
1024 |
||||
Potato | ||||||||
Production | 10678 |
1.45 |
10588 |
1.35 |
-90 |
-95 |
||
Consumption | 10732 |
1.43 |
10831 |
1.48 |
99 |
107 |
||
Net import | 54 |
243 |
189 |
202 |
||||
Other grains | ||||||||
Production | 24292 |
0.84 |
24360 |
0.93 |
68 |
14 |
||
Consumption | 24943 |
0.39 |
25810 |
1.01 |
867 |
498 |
||
Net import | 647 |
1450 |
803 |
485 |
||||
Total grains | ||||||||
Production | 463777 |
1.44 |
453145 |
1.02 |
-10632 |
-6272 |
||
Consumption | 483577 |
1.60 |
512753 |
2.69 |
29176 |
17130 |
||
Net import | 19799 |
59608 |
39809 |
23402 |
Note: Consumption (or demand) includes stock changes.
Table 13. Impacts of the trade liberalization (free trade) on livestock products and fish production, consumption, and trade, 2000-2005. | ||||||||
Baseline |
Free trade scenario |
Free trade vs baseline scenarios |
||||||
Commodity | In the year of 2005 (000 tons) |
Annual growth rate in 2000-05 (%) |
In the year of 2005 (000 tons) |
Annual growth rate in 2000-05 (%) |
Difference in 2005 (000 tons) |
Annual average difference in 2000-05 (000 tons) |
||
Pork | ||||||||
Production | 27703 |
3.39 |
31984 |
6.33 |
4281 |
2071 |
||
Consumption | 27462 |
3.43 |
25727 |
2.16 |
-1735 |
-839 |
||
Net import | -241 |
-6257 |
-6016 |
-2910 |
||||
Beef | ||||||||
Production | 3015 |
4.49 |
3090 |
4.94 |
75 |
39 |
||
Consumption | 2998 |
4.54 |
3119 |
5.49 |
121 |
53 |
||
Net import | -17 |
29 |
46 |
14 |
||||
Mutton | ||||||||
Production | 1746 |
4.35 |
1779 |
4.68 |
33 |
18 |
||
Consumption | 1745 |
4.36 |
1841 |
5.58 |
96 |
42 |
||
Net import | -0.5 |
62 |
63 |
24 |
||||
Poultry | ||||||||
Production | 7595 |
4.66 |
8683 |
7.42 |
1088 |
525 |
||
Consumption | 7885 |
4.61 |
7502 |
3.66 |
-383 |
-187 |
||
Net import | 290 |
-1181 |
-1471 |
-712 |
||||
Egg | ||||||||
Production | 14848 |
4.21 |
16478 |
6.32 |
1630 |
799 |
||
Consumption | 14817 |
4.21 |
14547 |
3.89 |
-270 |
-129 |
||
Net import | -31 |
-1931 |
-1900 |
-927 |
||||
Milk | ||||||||
Production | 9364 |
6.86 |
8888 |
5.68 |
-476 |
-209 |
||
Consumption | 9697 |
6.67 |
11716 |
10.90 |
2019 |
910 |
||
Net import | 333 |
2828 |
2495 |
1118 |
||||
Fish | ||||||||
Production | 15081 |
5.89 |
15721 |
6.72 |
640 |
307 |
||
Consumption | 14909 |
5.73 |
14581 |
5.37 |
-328 |
-169 |
||
Net import | -172 |
-1140 |
-968 |
-476 |
Note: the production and consumption data used in CAPSiM model are significantly different from the data published by the State Statistical Bureau. The database in CAPSiM on the livestock and aquatic production and consumption correct for the problems on over-reporting productions and under-estimating consumption of these products.
.........